Private Property: Rights, Responsibilities, & Limitations

December 12, 1999

PAER-1999-19

Jesse J. Richardson Jr.,* Assistant Professor in the Department of Urban Affairs and Planning at Virginia Tech and Gerald A. Harrison,** Extension Economist

Property rights are a concern for many landowners and are on legislators’ agendas even more now than in the past. In particular, property rights in land prompt much thought and debate in today’s political climate. Many property rights issues arise in the context of agriculture. This publication addresses frequently asked questions about property rights in land in order to dispel myths and misunderstandings and generate thoughtful discussion.

 

I can do whatever I choose with my land, right?

Yes, but within limits. Ownership of land extends from the sky to the lowest depths of the earth. The law holds property ownership in very high regard. Although landowners generally may do what they please with their land, there are limits on absolute ownership. Landowners are prohibited from using their property in a fashion that may injure their neighbors.

Property rights in land are often described by being compared to a bundle of sticks. Each stick represents a right. Each stick may be separated from the rest of the bundle. For instance, a land-owner may rent his land to one per-son to farm and transfer the underground mineral rights to another entity. The landowner in this situation still holds other sticks in the bundle (like the right to sell the land), though a sale may be subject to rights extended to others.

In all circumstances, government agencies at the local, state and federal level hold other rights such as the right to tax. Some sticks in your neighbor’s bundle, like the right to use her property in a beneficial fashion, may also affect your property.

 

How do you determine which land uses “injure” the neighbors?

Just as a property owner possesses rights to use his property, he also holds rights to prevent others from using their land in a manner that harms him or his property. “Nui-sance” describes a situation in which one landowner is using his property in a way that unreasonably limits the use of his neighbor’s land.

A “private nuisance” interferes with a relatively small number of people in their use of land. For example, if one neighbor plays her radio very loudly, especially during times that others sleep, that may constitute a private nuisance.

A “public nuisance” causes dis-tress to a large number of persons (an entire neighborhood or community) in the use of their land. For example, a cement factory, which discharges large amounts of smoke and dust, may amount to a public nuisance.

Who decides whether a particular activity is a nuisance?

The first step in deciding whether a landowner is injuring his neighbor is a complaint by the neighbor. Property rights depend in large part on whether persons are being good neighbors. The preferred way to resolve property rights disputes is to talk to your neighbor before you engage in an activity that may be offensive. If neighbors cannot agree, the offended neighbor may file a nuisance lawsuit. Then, a court will decide the issue.

How does a court decide whether an activity is a nuisance or not?

In determining whether one land-owner’s use of land is an “unreason-able” interference of another property owner’s use of land, the court must weigh many factors. On the one hand, the court must con-sider the extent of the harm, the character of the harm, the type of use being interfered with, and whether the use interfered with is appropriate to the area. On the other hand, the court must consider the benefits (income to the landowner, jobs, and tax revenue) provided by the offending use, whether the harm can be avoided with the continuation of the activity, and whether the offending use is suitable in that area. Courts balance these factors and con-sider other factors to resolve an issue.

What can courts do if they find a nuisance?

If a nuisance exists, the court has options in deciding what to do. The remedies may include money damages and/or an injunction. Money damages compensate the landowner for the interference with the use of his property. If the court orders the offending activity stopped, then the damages may be only for past injury. If the court allows the activity to continue, the damages may cover past and/or future injury.

An injunction is an order from a judge to stop an activity or a com-mand that a certain action may begin or continue. In the nuisance context, the judge most often orders the landowner to cease the nuisance activity. However, courts may com-bine damages and a partial injunction. A partial injunction would order the landowner to cut back the offending activity to a certain level. For example, if a judge found that a large hog operation was a nuisance, the judge may limit the farmer to a smaller number of hogs.

The law allows judges great flexibility in fashioning creative remedies. In an Arizona case, the judge ordered a large cattle feedlot to move, but made the developer of the adjoining residential subdivision pay for the move because the feedlot was there first. The solution to a nuisance case may involve a balanc-ing process to be fair, similar to the balancing used to determine whether a nuisance exists.

Do zoning regulations affect property rights?

Yes. The United States Constitution and court cases give government entities the power to pass laws to protect the health, safety, welfare, and morals of their citizens. This power is called the “police power.” Indiana and other states delegate this power, as it relates to land use, to local government units like cities and counties. With respect to land use, most local governments exercise their police powers through zoning ordinances. Zoning restrictions are intended to protect the health, safety, welfare, and morals of citizens.

Typical zoning ordinances divide the locality into districts. Within each district certain land uses are allowed, and certain other land uses are prohibited. The aim of typical zoning ordinances is to separate land uses. For example, all single family houses would be together and not beside a cement factory. Zoning laws are intended to avoid nuisances by prohibiting land activities that are potentially offensive to others. The United States Supreme Court has ruled that zoning ordinances may be valid exercises of the police power of state and local governments.

Can zoning prohibit me from putting a trailer on my property in which my elderly parents will live?

Yes. Zoning may prohibit using property in the way in which you want or in the way that may be most profit-able to you. The standard a court usually applies to determine whether zoning prohibitions are appropriate is the “arbitrary and capricious” standard. In other words, when local governments are acting to protect the health, safety, welfare, and morals of their citizens, the courts allow them broad discretion.

A court will usually overturn the local government’s zoning decision (for example, the denial of a request for a variance) if the decision is unreasonable and not supported by any facts. A court will not interfere with a land-use plan simply because a landowner has identified a more profitable use than is permitted by the plan.

Courts will also determine whether a zoning ordinance is for the public good, rather than for private gain. If the ordinance is for private gain, it is not valid. Again, one must look not only at a landowner’s property rights, but how the exercise of those property rights will affect neighbors and the community at large. Property ownership entails not only private rights, but also obligations to the public.

What if the government takes some of my land to build a road or other government facility?

Federal, state and local government agencies possess the power of eminent domain. An Indiana statute says private utilities may also possess the power of eminent domain for projects that benefit the public. Eminent domain pertains to the power of empowered agencies to acquire rights in private property to use for public purposes, even if the owner does not wish to sell. The Fifth Amendment of the United States Constitution provides that “… private property [shall not] be taken for public use without just compensation.”

Indiana’s as well as other states’ constitutions contain similar provisions. Any agency seeking to acquire private property rights for public use must follow steps in the law. Property owners may take action to insure fair compensation, or perhaps avoid the taking of their property in selected cases. Contact your lawyer or Purdue Extension for more information on eminent domain, condemnation and property rights.

The property owner must be paid a fair price. If the owner and the agency cannot agree on a price, then a procedure exists for the court to set the price usually after testimony from professional appraisers and due consideration to both sides. There-fore, the government and other enti-ties serving the public good may infringe on private property rights under legal procedures. The agency must pay an acceptable or objectively determined price.

Does the government have to pay when a regulation or law reduces the value of my property?

Local, state, and federal governments may regulate land and land uses. Most members of society recognize this legal fact. However, just as the law places limits on the ability of landowners to use their land as they please, legal constraints exist on a government’s ability to regulate land. The question may well be framed as “How far is too far?” In other words, how much may a government regulation reduce the value of a particular piece of private property before a “taking” occurs? When a government goes “too far” in regulating private property, it must pay just compensation.

The courts have struggled to define the point where governments have gone “too far” in regulating property. If the regulation is not for a “public purpose,” the government must pay compensation. A regulation may not exist only to further private interest. Further, the requirements imposed by the regulation must be directly connected to the public purpose. Only on rare occasions does a taking result from lack of public purpose.

Two other situations automatically merit compensation for the landowner. First, when the regulation acts to physically invade private property, such as requiring a land-owner to allow cable television wires on the landowner’s property, compensation must be paid. Any type of physical invasion, regardless of how small, warrants compensation.

Second, when the regulation makes a piece of property “worth-less,” compensation must be paid. “Worthless” in this context means no profitable uses exist after the regulation. A significant reduction in value may not entitle the landowner to automatic compensation.

If the regulatory taking does not fall into one of the categories mentioned above, a court considers the following factors to determine whether an unlawful taking has occurred:

  • the economic impact of the regulation on the landowner;
  • the landowner’s investment backed expectations; and,
  • the character of the government activity

No hard-and-fast rules exist to guide either the court or landowners in applying these factors. However, two examples may help illustrate the concepts involved.

First, suppose that the state government passes a law to protect wetlands. The law prohibits anyone from building, farming, or conducting any other activity on a wetland or within 1,000 feet of a wetland. Suppose you own a piece of land that is primarily wetlands. After this law is passed, you cannot put a building anywhere on your land, farm the land, or do anything with your land. In this case, the law has made your land worthless and an unconstitutional taking has occurred. The government must pay you for your land.

Now consider a situation in which you own farmland in Indiana. First it is zoned to allow you to use the property for offices or commercial purposes. Then it is rezoned so that now you may only build single-family dwellings. The land still retains value, so you may not assume that a total taking has occurred. The value of the land is much less than prior to the rezoning, however. In a suit for compensation, the court would have to balance the three factors listed above. A court would likely deter-mine that no taking has occurred in this situation.

Conclusion

The law regards property rights very highly and jealously guards their sanctity. However, each landowner possesses the right to use his or her land in a reasonable manner. This right may be affected by a neighbor’s use of his or her property. In these cases, where valid property rights of two or more persons exist, the respective property rights must be balanced to determine which right will prevail. A good neighbor policy of consulting with and giving advance notice to adjoining landowners can prevent many property rights disputes.

Similarly, the federal, local, and state governments may regulate land use. When there is a total or near total taking of one’s property, the law provides for compensation at fair market value. A drastic reduction in the value of your land due to a new regulation does not automatically entitle a landowner to compensation. Property rights must be balanced against the needs, rights, and concerns of all parties involved.

For their helpful suggestions and review of this publication, the authors wish to thank Steve Lovejoy and Gerald Shively, Purdue Department of Agricultural Economics; Mark Thornburg, Indiana Farm Bureau; and David C. Petritz, Purdue Extension.

This information is available as ID-229. Additional references for this paper are available from Gerald A. Harrison. More land use resources are available at your Purdue Cooperative Extension Service Office.

You make obtain a reader entitled “Takings Law in Plain English,” 47 pages, by sending $4.00 (payable to Purdue University) to Gerald Harrison. Gerry Harrison’s Ag Law Course Internet site includes several references for ag law topics such as “conservation easements,” “lease law,”

“fence law” which may be accessed at: <http://www.agecon.purdue.edu/academic/agec455/>.

 

* Jesse J. Richardson, Jr. is a member of the Virginia Bar.

** Gerald A. Harrison is a member of the Indiana Bar.

Tags

Publication Appeared Within:

Latest Articles:

Does a higher standard deduction decrease cash donations and volunteering?

October 24, 2024

Tax policy shapes individuals’ incentives to give to charities. In fact, taxpayers can deduct charitable cash contributions as an itemized deduction, which decreases their taxable income and leads to a lower tax bill. Itemizing deductions, however, is not convenient for all taxpayers. Moreover, the standard deduction is the better option for those whose total itemized deductions for eligible expenses are lower than the current standard deduction. Taxpayers choose between the standard deduction and itemized deductions based on which yields the lower amount of taxable income and, hence, tax liability.

READ MORE

Farmland Prices Increase Despite Downward Pressure

August 9, 2024

Indiana farmland prices reached record highs in 2024, with top-quality land averaging $14,392 per acre, a 4.8% increase from 2023, according to the Purdue Farmland Value and Cash Rent Survey. Regional variations and market forces like high interest rates and low land supply influenced the market, while long-term projections suggest continued modest growth. Transition land saw a significant 21.6% rise, while recreational land values dipped slightly.

READ MORE

Trends in Farmland Price to Rent Ratios in Indiana, 2024

August 9, 2024

Farmland prices in west central Indiana increased slightly in 2024 (0.2%) and are 19.7% above the previous peak in 2014. Compared to the farmland price in 2007, current farmland prices in west central Indiana are 187% higher. Farmland prices are influenced by many factors, including net income, growth in earnings, crop and livestock prices, interest rates, alternative investment returns, inflation, liquidity, agricultural policy, and energy policy. Cash rent, which is influenced by net return to land, along with interest rates, is often referred to as a fundamental factor impacting farmland prices.

READ MORE

Delivered right to your inbox

The Purdue Agricultural Economics Report is a quarterly publication written by faculty and staff from the Department Agricultural Economics at Purdue University.

By joining this mailing list, you will receive an email when a new publication is released. This mailing list is kept solely for the purpose of sharing the report and is not used for any other purposes.